U.S. Political Thought

Lecture 11


November 7, 1995
Joseph Boland

Outline

    Lecture Outline
  1. Introduction
  2. The Process of Industrialization
  3. Conclusion

Lecture

I. Introduction

The Civil War and the industrial revolution brought abrupt, radical and in many respects violent change to the political, economic, and social landscape of America. The title of this segment of the course, “responses to industrialization,” reflects this. In one way or another, all of the readings included here were efforts to make sense of something which had already occurred. In this light, they were reactions. But these readings also show how intellectual elites and social movements gained insight into the inner dynamics of industrialization and into the larger consequences of the sectional settlement that marked the end of Reconstruction (on the sectional party system, see especially Goodwyn). This, in turn, led them to formulate original ideas for social reform (Croly, Addams) or revolt (the Populists, Debs); for justifying the existing features of industrial society (Sumner); and for reframing the ideals of the American republic (all of the authors). The readings thus offer creative answers to the social and cultural crises of early industrialization: the social welfare state (Croly); a Social Darwinist form of neo-liberalism (Sumner); American socialism (Debs); radical republicanism (the Populists); and a communicative, scientific, and communal democracy (Dewey, Addams). Nor do these readings by any means exhaust the range of critical and creative thought from the period.

Before examining these works individually, it is important to consider some of the distinctive features of the newly industrialized society. We haven’t the time to attempt an historical review of industrialization, but we can attempt to single out the most problematic qualities of industrial society and indicate how those qualities were rooted in the industrialization process itself. What we gain by this, hopefully, is a better understanding of the social environment to which these works are addressed.

II. The Process of Industrialization

The Civil War as the womb of industrialization: The Civil War not only gave an immense boost to capitalist industrial development, it also contributed to its national, rather than regional or state-centered, focus. War time consumption by the national government boosted industrial output and advanced the commercialization of agriculture. War time borrowing by government greatly expanded the money supply and thus both the amount of investment capital and the aggregate purchasing capacity. With the South’s secession the national government fell under the control of a party very sympathetic to Northern industrial interests (the Republican party), and it quickly passed laws favorable to industry. These included higher protective tariffs, approval of a transcontinental railroad funded through enormous land grants, and establishment of a new banking system. The war expanded the power and authority of the federal government while diminishing that of the states.

Industrialization was extraordinarily rapid: In thirty years industrial capacity and output increased over five-fold. “By 1860, $1 billion had been invested in American industry, and the factories and shops that made up our industrial community produced goods that year valued at about $1.8 billion. By 1890, the capitalization of industry had soared to $6.5 billion, and the annual value of industrial production approached $10 billion” (Hofstadter et. al., 473). By 1890 the United States was the leading manufacturing nation in the world. Another crude measure of the pace of change comes from patent records. In the entire history of the United States up to 1860, only 36,000 patents had been granted. For the period from 1860 to 1890, the figure was 440,000.

It was marked by a sudden shift from a rural, agrarian society to an urban one dominated by factories: After the 1890 census, the Census Bureau announced the closing of the frontier. There were no more large tracts of land open for settlement. At the same time, technological change made farming far more productive per farm worker but also more capital intensive. The influence of the ideal of an agrarian republic waned with the decline of the farming population and the thorough commercialization of agriculture. The ranks of the industrial working class swell, and a new middle class of corporate and public sector professionals emerges. By 1898 there were 17,000,000 million workers. The proportion of people living in cities doubled between 1860 and 1900, from 16% to 33%. Many cities experienced enormous growth spurts. Between 1850 and 1900 New York’s population increased from 1,200,000 to over 3,000,000, Pittsburgh’s from 67,000 to 450,000, and Chicago’s from 30,000 to 1,700,000. Urban growth is chaotic--virtually devoid of planning or zoning, controlled by private real estate interests, and marked by often unrestricted pollution of water, land and air. Urban political machines often provided protection and patronage to ethnic immigrants, but also tended to be very corrupt.

It established an economy dominated by large corporations: Before the Civil War, the corporate form of organization was confined to a few sectors of the economy. After the war, it became the leading form of economic organization. It allowed the wealth of thousands of investors to be pooled, and it enabled the firm to continue in existence despite changes in leadership (unlike partnerships or single proprietorships, which were liable to dissolution or reorganization when one of the principals departed). It protected the personal wealth of investors by the legal mechanism of limited liability, according to which investors were only liable for a corporation’s obligations to the extent of their own investment. Rulings by the Supreme Court from 1886 onward interpreted the Fourteenth Amendment so as to make corporations legal persons entitled to “due process” of law, weakening the states’ power of regulation.

Around the corporate economy new classes formed: an executive class at the top, as mergers built giant corporations and interlocking directorships facilitated cooperation among them; professional (and moderate stock-owning) classes in the middle; below them an industrial working class (itself stratified by skill, ethnicity, and other factors); and at the bottom, the destitute and the vagrant. Stock ownership was an important means by which many American of moderate means came to have a stake in the success of this economy (though stock manipulation by rich insiders also ruined some of them). By 1900 about 4,400,000 persons had investments in American corporations.

Periodic economic crises and the constant threat of ruinous competition inspired a search for stable bases of profitability, a search that varied with the condition of particular firms, industrial sectors, and the overall economy. The wave of mergers and buy-outs that occurred around the turn of the century was one expression of this. Concentration facilitated price-fixing and the division of markets. Spreading networks of interlocking directorates was another, since these enhanced businesses’ ability to negotiate agreements among themselves and blurred boundaries between firms that shared directors. The growing power of finance capital was a third stabilizing force, since it gave a handful of leading bankers the ability to rationalize groups of firms and even whole sectors of the economy. Government regulation, particularly federal regulation, was a fourth method of stabilization. Federal regulations could impose uniform requirements on an industry, for example uniform rates on railroads, thus limiting competition. Regulations could also be used as “entrance barriers,” raising the costs facing new firms wishing to enter a market.

The movement away from pure competitive capitalism was rooted in the process of capitalist industrialization itself. Competition, especially when combined with an accelerating pace of organizational and technical improvement, resulted in periodic overproduction, driving weaker firms bankrupt and precipitating depressions. Over time, this resulted in growing concentration of ownership, especially in older sectors, for example steel (US Steel), oil (Standard Oil), and the railroads (J. P. Morgan).

It created a new infrastructure for transportation, communication, and coordination and control: In 1873, there were 70,000 miles of railroad. In just the next 20 years, another 100,000 miles of track were laid. This period saw the invention and widespread use of the telegraph (195,000 miles owned by Western Union in 1878) and the telephone (invented in 1876, long distance service introduced in 1884).

A predominantly immigrant urban working class endured harsh working conditions yet faced very difficult obstacles to organizing: There was very little in the way of regulations governing wages, hours, or working conditions. Workers who suffered on the job injuries or who were not paid according to their expectations often had no legal alternative other than filing a civil suit for damages, an expensive proposition. The Sherman Anti-Trust Act (1890), intended to curb the formation of trusts and other monopolies, was interpreted by the Supreme Court to prohibit strikes by unions against any firm engaged in interstate commerce, on the grounds that this constituted a restraint of trade. In general, the political and judicial climate was very anti-union.

The sharp cycles of the economy meant that workers faced periods of high unemployment when they weren’t working 60-80 hours a week for six or seven days a week. In addition, through the time and motion studies of Frederick Taylor and others and with the invention of the assembly line and other technological and organizational improvements, work was accelerated while becoming at the same time more monotonous and “deskilled.”

Labor organizing faced other problems besides opposition from employers and the state. The cultural and linguistic diversity of the working class and the unfamiliarity of many with the laws and customs of the new country was one. Many immigrants, moreover, were actually migrant laborers who intended to return once they had saved enough money to start over. Looking upon their work in America as temporary, they hoped for deliverance from its difficulties through emigration, not social transformation. Emigration back home varied between 30 and 40 percent of immigration from the 1880s through 1914.

Another obstacle to organizing was the ethnic stratification of workers. The influx of immigrants was a boon to native born workers, who were moved into lower managerial and administrative positions and--along with skilled British and German workers--into higher paying craft jobs. This stratification was reinforced by the American Federation of Labor, which was not an organization of workers but of craft unions, and which was dedicated to protecting the privileged positions of unionized craft workers.

Finally, belief in social mobility--the Horatio Alger dream of going from rags to riches--undoubtedly weakened efforts to forge solidarity among workers.

As a result of these and other problems, of the 17,000,000 million workers in 1898, only 500,000 were unionized.

III. Conclusion

Industrialization created much wider disparities of wealth and power than Americans had been familiar with (apart from the institution of slavery). It virtually destroyed the older agrarian republican ideal of economic independence within community by completing the commercialization of agriculture and by creating new industrial classes. Not only workers and farmers but even members of the new corporate-public sector middle class were keenly aware that their economic existence and social security were largely dependent upon a combination of impersonal market forces and distant centers of economic and political power. Large institutions, corporations and “trusts” most of all, seemed to dwarf the powers of communities and common citizens. Beginning with the flagrant corruption of the Grant administration (1868-1876), governments of the period, from urban machines to the federal Congress and executive, were often outrageously corrupt and prostrate before the newly rich industrial “robber barons” and their smaller cousins in the new metropolises.

If there is a common thread linking the readings in this segment, it is that each responds to the new realities of mammoth corporate and governmental powers, the consequent erosion of democratic institutions, the breakdown of older forms of community life, and the dangers of escalating civil strife. The authors generally attempt both to specify needed social reforms (or, in the case of Sumner, to justify existing conditions) and to rearticulate or reinvent traditional ideologies--particularly those of liberalism, republicanism and the Christian social ethic--in light of radically changed conditions. In doing so, they also incorporate new thinking, such as Social Darwinism (Sumner), an appreciation for scientific rationality (Dewey), “producerism” and the monetary thinking behind the call for “fiat money” (the Populists), Marxism (Debs), and so on.